Who actually pays for credit card fraud? (part II)


[continued from part I, which provides background]

The answer to the burning question of who gets to pay for fraudulent credit-card transactions is influenced by many factors. On the one hand there are the particulars of the situation that vary between each incident: whether it was a stolen card, where the charges took place and how quickly the card-holder contacted their financial institution. At the other extreme, there are large-scale policy issues decided for the entire ecosystem by regulatory regimes for consumer protection. For example in Europe, part of the reason EMV adoption happened in a hurry is that banks seized the opportunity to shift presumption of guilt to consumers. This so-called “liability shift” was predicated on the assumption that because EMV cards are very unlikely to be cloned or used without knowledge of the PIN (an incorrect assumption on many levels, it turns out due to vulnerabilities in the design that are being exploited in the wild) the burden of proof is on the card-holder to prove that they did not in fact.

In the US, there is a belief that consumers are not liable for credit-card fraud. It is a simple message to communicate, which makes it a common refrain for advertising/PR campaigns encouraging consumers to swipe those cards liberally without fear. It sounds reassuring. It is also not entirely accurate.

On the one hand, it is true that the US model starts out with a presumption of innocence. When the card-holder contests a charge, the bank temporarily suspends it while an investigation is under way. But more importantly, the burden of proof on consumer side is much lower. Unless the retailer can prove that the customer in fact made the purchase or at least show they have done due diligence by producing a signed receipt, they are on the hook. (That also means for card-not-present purchases such as those happening on the Internet, the merchant is very likely going to be the one eating the loss.) If there is evidence of card-holder participation, it is now between issuer and consumer to decide. The signature on the receipt could have been forged, indicating a cloned card, or perhaps the merchant authorized a different amount than originally agreed. In all cases, unless the parties in question can prove conclusively that a card-holder knowingly authorized that exact charge, the losses are absorbed by issuing bank or merchant.

In theory this is a very consumer-friendly regime. All the while surprising that it has gained traction in the US, while Europe with its tradition of consumer protection would favor the opposite. It places incentives for combating fraud on the parties most capable of taking action. Issuers can refine their statistical models to better distinguish legitimate vs fraudulent activity, meanwhile merchants can implement policies based on their risk/benefit calculations. For example online merchants may refuse to ship to addresses other than the billing address on the card, retailers may ask to check ID for large purchases, meanwhile Starbucks can define its own threshold above which signatures are required even if it means slowing down the line. That still leaves open one question: what happens to the losses that issuers and merchants still incur after all of these mitigations have been implemented?

Indiscriminate insurance

Imagine a car insurance company that charges all drivers the same rate, regardless of their demographics (no over-charging young people living alone to subsidize older married couples), past driving record or the current value of their vehicle. This is in effect how credit-card losses are distributed throughout the payment system.

Not being directly liable for fraudulent charges is not the same as being completely off the hook. US regulatory frameworks may have conspired with the card networks’ own business model to off-load losses away from card holders and towards merchants & issuers. But there is no rule that dictates those parties may not pass those costs on to consumers in the form of higher prices. In fact this concern comes up for merchants even in the absence of fraud.  Recall that a credit-card purchase could involve upwards of 3% fee compared to a cash purchase. (If that sounds negligible, consider that some retailers such as grocery stores have razor-thin profit margins less than 5%. In effect they are giving up half of their profit, which goes a long way towards explaining why Wal-Mart, Target etc. were highly motivated to spearhead a merchant consortium to create alternative payment rails.) The economically rational behavior would be to introduce a surcharge for credit card purchases. The reason that did not happen in practice is that it ran afoul of Visa/MasterCard rules until recently. In 2013 a court settlement finally allowed merchants to start passing on costs to consumers but only in certain states.

A similar situation applies to dispersing the effect of fraud. If merchants are setting prices based on the expectation that they will lose a certain percent of revenues to fraud, all customers are sharing in that cost. The bizarre part is that customers are not even subsidizing each other any longer, but complete strangers with no business relationship to the retailer. Imagine consumer Bob has his credit-card information stolen and used at some electronics retailer for a fraudulent purchase, even though Bob himself never shops there. When consumer Alice later frequents the same store, she is in effect paying a slightly higher price to make up for the charge-back caused by crooks using Bob’s card.

Moral hazard?

Same calculus applies on the issuer side, except there is arguably a greater element of individual responsibility. This time it is not about a specific “price” charged to consumers per se, but subtle adjustments to terms of credit for accommodating expected losses. For example, the annual fee for the privilege of carrying the card might be a little higher, its APR on balances set to a few basis points higher or the rewards program a little less generous. If Alice and Bob were both customers of the same bank and Bob experiences fraudulent charges because he typed his credit-card information into a phishing page, Alice is indirectly paying for that moment of carelessness.

Whatever one might say about the virtues of this system, fairness is not one of its defining features. The system provides Bob with peace of mind in the same way that insurance will pay for repairing a car after the owner repeatedly drives it into a ditch. Unlike car insurance, costs are not reflected on specific individuals with increased premiums. Instead fraud losses are socialized across the entire customer base. Now in fairness to Bob, he may not have been responsible for the breach. Even the most cautious and responsible card-holder has little control over whether Target or Home Depot point-of-sale terminals have been compromised by malware that captures card details in the course of a routine purchase. What could be more routine than using a credit card at a reputable nation-wide retailer in an actual bricks-and-mortar store? Neither can Bob compensate for fundamental design weaknesses in payment protocols, such as the ease of cloning magnetic stripes by unilaterally upgrading himself to chip&PIN card.

[continued]

CP

Leave a Reply

Please log in using one of these methods to post your comment:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s